This post originally appeared on The Co-Op, a blog of young(ish) writers of varying ideological and political perspectives.
Technology is going to change the way we work. In the research group that I work in, we have two Baxter robots. These humanoid robots are designed to effectively replace human workers in low-skill manual tasks, particularly in industrial environments. They’ve already been put in some factories in the US, particularly in small businesses. Earlier this year, researchers at Columbia University showed how a Baxter robot combined with machine learning could iron clothes. I published a paper earlier this year where Baxter could play chess against a human. Every day more applications are being revealed. These robots cost about US$25,000, which sounds like a lot until you consider that it’s roughly one year’s salary for a low-skilled worker. The robot doesn’t need to rest, it doesn’t get sick, it doesn’t need holiday pay, and generally achieves a lower error rate than a bored human doing repetitive tasks all day.
Technology is going to change the way we work. In the research group that I work in, we have two Baxter robots. These humanoid robots are designed to effectively replace human workers in low-skill manual tasks, particularly in industrial environments. They’ve already been put in some factories in the US, particularly in small businesses. Earlier this year, researchers at Columbia University showed how a Baxter robot combined with machine learning could iron clothes. I published a paper earlier this year where Baxter could play chess against a human. Every day more applications are being revealed. These robots cost about US$25,000, which sounds like a lot until you consider that it’s roughly one year’s salary for a low-skilled worker. The robot doesn’t need to rest, it doesn’t get sick, it doesn’t need holiday pay, and generally achieves a lower error rate than a bored human doing repetitive tasks all day.
Automation, industrial or otherwise, is treated like
the bane of the low-skilled worker. For researchers, simple tasks are
the easiest place to start, and the technology already exists to make
hundreds of types of jobs redundant – the main barrier is that it’s
currently economically unviable to implement. The fear is that
introducing this technology will cause mass unemployment and widening
inequality. The traditional economic response to this is usually “well
people can just upskill”, which is fine as a principle but not practical
for many people. Upskilling requires education, education costs time
and money, and not everyone has access to the necessary resources or
support to “just upskill”. Even when everyone does upskill, there may
not be enough jobs for all the upskilled people – just ask the legal
industry.
The Universal
Basic Income (UBI) seems like an attractive option to help alleviate the
pressures on all people as their jobs become more uncertain and
insecure. If we can provide every person in the country with a base
level of income from the government sufficient for some minimum standard
of living, then work is no longer a necessity for survival, but
something that we do because we want to. We become more incentivised to
find fulfilling work, not just work with sufficient income. Individuals
become willing to take larger risks such as starting up small businesses
or moving into unpaid education or volunteer work because the UBI
safety net can catch them if they fail. Social welfare becomes a lot
simpler, and the government doesn’t need to somewhat arbitrarily decide
who is deserving of a benefit and who isn’t. I don’t necessarily agree
that the UBI is the correct or only answer, but I accept that the UBI is
one potential solution to address technological unemployment. However,
if we are going to debate the merits of having a UBI we need to consider
an important point.
My main concern with a UBI as a solution to
technological unemployment is the nature of time. People losing their
jobs due to advancements in technology happens gradually and in small
pockets of society. In the past, this has been slow enough that humans
have generally been able to adapt. When I say slow, I mean over the
course of years or decades. Artisan weavers were replaced by mechanised
looms, and while some people were hurt by losing their jobs, there was
no broader societal upset. More recently, retail cashiers have been
replaced by self-service checkouts, but this isn’t necessarily seen as a
direct cause of rising unemployment. Most of these changes have been
small in scale because technology doesn’t change jobs on a large scale
overnight – the human element ensures that technology is introduced
slowly and cautiously. Business owners are conservative, and don’t like
risking the future of their businesses on some technological fad that
might be outdated within six months. Technological unemployment is a
continuous process, not discrete.
In most proposals for UBIs,
the policy change would have to be instantaneous. One day, everyone is
paying a certain level of tax and getting nothing (or a benefit), the
next day new legislation kicks in and suddenly everyone is paying a
different level of tax and getting a $11,000 a year. This implies that
we have to identify some threshold where we say “okay, enough people
have lost their jobs to technology, the UBI is needed now.” In the
meantime, all the people below that threshold who have already lost
their jobs will suffer. Perhaps we’ve already started to see this, with
rising homelessness, rising inequality, and rising job volatility. When
we apply utilitarian macroeconomics and tax policies, individuals fall
through the cracks all too easily. We either have to wait for the
problem to worsen and for some tipping point to happen, or bring in the
policy too early and encounter unnecessary costs.
So perhaps, if we are going to have a UBI, what we
need is unfortunately complicated – a gradual, slow increase of the UBI
to match the gradual, slow changes to the labour market. Any policy
implementation has to be discrete, putting it at odds with the
continuous nature of technological unemployment, but at least making
many small steps might be better than making one big step. So rather
than jumping straight to $200 a week per person (and bankrupting the
government), maybe we need to start at $200 a month or every two months.
It’s not enough to live on, but it’s enough to start sending signals to
society that the way we think about work and labour is going to change.
Make it opt-in too so that people have to actively participate and
understand what’s happening in order to benefit. We’d still have to
initially keep some forms of social welfare benefits like jobseeker
support (unemployment benefit) to help people transition between jobs
(perhaps the amounts paid out for benefits can decrease as the UBI level
increases). But over time, as technology makes our society more wealthy
and prosperous, the UBI can increase sustainably to a level that
supports all people in our country. It may feel like small drops in a
bucket, but maybe that’s exactly what we need rather than pouring a jug
of water into the bucket and watching it overflow.
Some would argue that this is difficult to do because
it increases compliance costs, it becomes harder to educate people how
this scheme works, and it become susceptible to over-reactions to
short-term fluctuations rather than long-term trends. For some reason,
when it comes to tax policy or social welfare policy we wait for ages
and ages for changes to happen because we don’t want to confuse people
by changing it too often. What I’m advocating for is a number of small
changes more frequently, rather than one big change and then waiting a
long time to revisit it. We already do this with the Official Cash Rate –
we recognise that it’s important that for the Reserve Bank to react to
the changing macroeconomic environment eight times a year rather than
just once a year. Why shouldn’t we also be reacting to the changing
labour market in the same way?
Of course, any
movement towards a UBI requires a substantial change in how the
government raises revenue too, whether that includes a true
capital-gains tax on all assets, changing the tax brackets to increase
the contributions of the super-rich, and/or creating incentives for
multinationals to keep their money in New Zealand and pay tax rather
than taking the profits overseas. The government’s expenditures would
have to change too, with a hard look at superannuation, tariffs and
subsidies, and social welfare more broadly too. But each of these policy
changes should stand on its own merits independently, as well as
together when considered in context. We can talk about whether a UBI
makes sense and how to best implement it first, so that it can become a
key plank of a model for how government can support society in uncertain
times.
No comments:
Post a Comment